In the last post (paste link here) I
discussed how the reputation of a mutual fund plays a crucial role in
determining how investors react to fund's recent performance. In this post, I
shift my attention from investors to mutual fund managers. Here I discuss some
results from my latest work on the behavior of fund managers. By behavior I
mean the way manager forms his portfolio (portfolio is nothing but a bundle of
asset and it is usual in finance it sometimes also means the investment
strategy) and manage the risk in his investments. In my paper I study how the
historic performance of a fund alters its risk taking behavior. Before
proceeding, let's understand what matters for fund manager. Managerial
incentives are two dimensional: on one hand he has to attract capital from
investors as ultimately his compensation depends upon the size of the fund he
manages. On the other hand he is answerable to fund management and his
employment contract depends upon his performance. We have already seen in the
last post that investor reaction depends upon historic performance together
with current performance. Data suggest that reputation or history of
performance also matters for employment continuation. In my sample, 30\% of the
managers who are fired from their job ranked within bottom 20\% in terms of
their historic performance. Clearly, having a poor history raises the
probability of firing. (Else the number should have been 20\% instead of 30\%.
Think!) Clearly we know now that a poor history fund manager is facing a
serious unemployment risk as compared to a good history fund manager. So there
is a strong case to believe that reputation must matter for the way managers
handle their investments during current period.
In 1996, Brown, Harlow and Starks (BHS
hereafter) came up with a study which found that a midyear losing manager is
more likely to bump-up the risk of his portfolio in the second half of the
year. But later studies did not find strong support for this evidence. Kemph,
Ruenzi and Theile published a research in 2007 doing a very simple trick. They
argued that compensation incentives are more dominant during the period when
stock market performs well but employment incentives are strong during bad
years. So managers might manage risk differently over good and bad years. I
combine Kemph's approach and include the reputation as a new driver of
managerial risk taking ability. So we are interested in analyzing how managers
change their investment risk profile in the later half of the year as compared
to first half of the year, given their mid-year performance position. It is
important to know a good measure of risk in this context: it is precisely the
extent to which manager deviate away from what their peers are doing. So risk
is measured using how much manager's returns deviate away from benchmark. Then
change in risk is just risk in the second half of the year minus risk in the
first of the year. I prefer to take the ratio of second half risk to the first
half risk, so that the ratio of 1 is status quo.
What I find is pretty interesting.
First I find that midyear position has no impact whatsoever on risk-shifting
during good years. Only during bad years, when unemployment risk is higher do
the managers try to adjust the risk. Following figure shows the results for bad
years: On X-axis we have mid-year rank (0 being lowest and 1 being highest) and
on Y-axis we have risk-shifting ratio: ratio of risk during second half to
first half. What we have on our hands is really a fascinating result: As the
mid-year performance gets better, top reputed funds reduce this ratio and low
reputed funds increase this ratio. (Note the ratio is more than 1 for any
reputation and mid-year position. So it is a general trend that all funds
bump-up their risk during second half anyway. We want to understand how the
extent of that change with mid-year performance). This is a dramatically opposite behavior.
How can we explain it? There are two
dimensions we need to explain. First is how the manager behavior change as
mid-year position change and second comparing the levels of the risk-shifting
for top and low reputation managers. I answer these one by one. First, top
reputed manager has lower risk of getting fired with one-off bad performance,
so these managers bump-up the risk more during second half of the year as
compared to low reputed managers when in a mid-year losing position. That
explains why the curve for top guys starts at a higher level. Second, as
mid-year performance improve, top guys want to play it safe. This is because
even a reasonable performance during the year assures them employment next
period and also we know from my last post that a bad performance by top guys is
penalized more by investors. So given a reasonable mid-year position there is
no point in bumping up the risk. That explains why risk-shifting curve slopes
downwards for top guys. Now coming to low reputed managers: For low reputation
guys, if they are in a reasonable mid-year position, it gives them some
head-start to capitalize and they have incentive to bump-up the risk. This is
gambling for resurrection. But as their mid-year performance gets bad, their
risk appetite goes down very much as unemployment risk bites them. So their
objective is not to be a topper anymore but just be a median guy, so they keep
if very safe, having portfolios very similar to their peers. This explains why
curve slopes upwards for low reputed guys.
Of course all these are conjectures and
it is important to write down a proper theory to see if this logic holds in a
rational model. But what the results show is very interesting and important
from the compensation designing perspective. Fund management teams can
optimally construct the salary schemes so as to keep managerial risk-shifting
in control and what my results shows is that managers need to have element in
their salary to hedge against unemployment risk. Otherwise, managers are probe
to risk-shifting!
No comments:
Post a Comment